Automatic stabiliser: Difference between revisions
No edit summary |
mNo edit summary |
||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
In [[macroeconomics]] '''automatic |
In [[macroeconomics]] '''automatic stabilisers''' work as a tool to dampen fluctuations in [[real GDP]] without any explicit policy action by the government. It is a government program that changes automatically depending on GDP and a person’s income,<ref>{{cite book |
||
| last = Sullivan |
| last = Sullivan |
||
| first = arthur |
| first = arthur |
||
Line 37: | Line 37: | ||
This means that ''government expenditure increases automatically in recessions and decreases automatically in a boom'' in absolute terms. Since the trend of output is to increase in booms and decrease in recessions, expenditure is expected to increase as a share of income in recessions and decrease as a share of income in booms. |
This means that ''government expenditure increases automatically in recessions and decreases automatically in a boom'' in absolute terms. Since the trend of output is to increase in booms and decrease in recessions, expenditure is expected to increase as a share of income in recessions and decrease as a share of income in booms. |
||
==When |
==When stabilisers don't work== |
||
There is broad consensus amongst economists that the automatic |
There is broad consensus amongst economists that the automatic stabilisers often exist and function in the short term. |
||
However, the automatic |
However, the automatic stabilisers model does not incorporate [[rational expectations]] or other [[microfoundations]]. No part of economics is in the final analysis a mechanistic process and the existence of the stabilisers can easily be overshadowed by other changes to policy, expectations or markets. |
||
==Automatic |
==Automatic stabilisers incorporated into the expenditure multiplier== |
||
This section incorporates automatic stabilisation into a broadly [[Keynesian]] [[Multiplier (economics)|multiplier]] model. |
This section incorporates automatic stabilisation into a broadly [[Keynesian]] [[Multiplier (economics)|multiplier]] model. |
||
<math>Multiplier=\frac{1}{1-[MPC(1-T) |
<math>Multiplier=\frac{1}{1-[MPC(1-T)-MPI]}</math> |
||
*'''MPC''' = [[Marginal propensity to consume]] |
*'''MPC''' = [[Marginal propensity to consume]] |
||
*'''T''' = Induced taxes |
*'''T''' = Induced taxes |
||
Line 52: | Line 52: | ||
Holding all other things constant, [[ceteris paribus]], the greater the level of taxes, or the greater the MPI then the value of this multiplier will drop. For example, lets assume that: |
Holding all other things constant, [[ceteris paribus]], the greater the level of taxes, or the greater the MPI then the value of this multiplier will drop. For example, lets assume that: |
||
:→ ''MPC'' = 0. |
:→ ''MPC'' = 0.8 |
||
:→ ''T'' = 0 |
:→ ''T'' = 0 |
||
Line 62: | Line 62: | ||
Lets now take an economy where there are positive taxes (an increase from 0 to 0.2), while the MPC and MPI remain the same: |
Lets now take an economy where there are positive taxes (an increase from 0 to 0.2), while the MPC and MPI remain the same: |
||
:→ ''MPC'' = 0. |
:→ ''MPC'' = 0.8 |
||
:→ ''T'' = 0.2 |
:→ ''T'' = 0.2 |
||
Line 68: | Line 68: | ||
:→ ''MPI'' = 0.2 |
:→ ''MPI'' = 0.2 |
||
If these figures were now substituted into the multiplier formula, the resulting figure would be ''' |
If these figures were now substituted into the multiplier formula, the resulting figure would be '''1.79'''. This figure would give us the instance where, again, a $1 billion change in expenditure would now lead to only a $1.79 billion change in equilibrium real GDP. |
||
This example shows us how the multiplier is lessened by the existence of an automatic |
This example shows us how the multiplier is lessened by the existence of an automatic stabiliser, and thus helping to lessen the fluctuations in real GDP as a result from changes in expenditure. Not only does this example work with changes in '''T''', it would also work by changing the '''MPI''' while holding '''MPC''' and '''T''' constant as well. |
||
== See also == |
== See also == |
Revision as of 11:59, 16 June 2010
In macroeconomics automatic stabilisers work as a tool to dampen fluctuations in real GDP without any explicit policy action by the government. It is a government program that changes automatically depending on GDP and a person’s income,[1] and acts as a negative feedback loop on GDP.
The size of the government deficit tends to increase as a country enters recession, which helps keep national income high through the multiplier.
Furthermore, imports often tend to decrease in a recession, meaning more of the national income is spent at home rather than abroad. This also helps stabilise the economy.
Induced taxes
Government tax revenue tends to fall as a proportion of national income during recessions.
This occurs because of the way tax systems are generally constructed.
- Income tax is generally at least somewhat progressive. If an individual's income rises, then their average tax rate increases. This means that as incomes fall, households pay less as a proportion of their income in direct taxation.
- Corporation tax is generally based on profits, rather than turnover. In a recession profits tend to fall much faster than turnover. Therefore, a corporation pays much less tax while having only slightly less economic activity.
If national income rises, by contrast, then both households and corporations end up paying higher proportions of their income in tax.
This means that in an economic boom tax revenue is higher and in a recession tax revenue lower; not only in absolute terms but as a proportion of national income.
Other forms of tax do not exhibit these effects, because they are roughly proportionate to income (e.g. taxes on consumption like sales tax or value added tax, or they bear no relation to income (e.g. poll tax or property tax).
Transfer payments
Most governments also pay unemployment and welfare benefits. Generally speaking, the number of unemployed people and those on low incomes who are entitled to other benefits increases in a recession and decreases in a boom.
This means that government expenditure increases automatically in recessions and decreases automatically in a boom in absolute terms. Since the trend of output is to increase in booms and decrease in recessions, expenditure is expected to increase as a share of income in recessions and decrease as a share of income in booms.
When stabilisers don't work
There is broad consensus amongst economists that the automatic stabilisers often exist and function in the short term.
However, the automatic stabilisers model does not incorporate rational expectations or other microfoundations. No part of economics is in the final analysis a mechanistic process and the existence of the stabilisers can easily be overshadowed by other changes to policy, expectations or markets.
Automatic stabilisers incorporated into the expenditure multiplier
This section incorporates automatic stabilisation into a broadly Keynesian multiplier model.
- MPC = Marginal propensity to consume
- T = Induced taxes
- MPI = Marginal Propensity to Import
Holding all other things constant, ceteris paribus, the greater the level of taxes, or the greater the MPI then the value of this multiplier will drop. For example, lets assume that:
- → MPC = 0.8
- → T = 0
- → MPI = 0.2
Here we have an economy with zero marginal taxes and zero transfer payments. If these figures were substituted into the multiplier formula, the resulting figure would be 2.5. This figure would give us the instance where a (for instance) $1 billion change in expenditure would lead to a $2.5 billion change in equilibrium real GDP.
Lets now take an economy where there are positive taxes (an increase from 0 to 0.2), while the MPC and MPI remain the same:
- → MPC = 0.8
- → T = 0.2
- → MPI = 0.2
If these figures were now substituted into the multiplier formula, the resulting figure would be 1.79. This figure would give us the instance where, again, a $1 billion change in expenditure would now lead to only a $1.79 billion change in equilibrium real GDP.
This example shows us how the multiplier is lessened by the existence of an automatic stabiliser, and thus helping to lessen the fluctuations in real GDP as a result from changes in expenditure. Not only does this example work with changes in T, it would also work by changing the MPI while holding MPC and T constant as well.
See also
References
- ^ Sullivan, arthur (2003). Economics: Principles in action. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey 07458: Pearson Prentice Hall. p. 399. ISBN 0-13-063085-3.
{{cite book}}
: Unknown parameter|coauthors=
ignored (|author=
suggested) (help)CS1 maint: location (link)